Poly sacks, post-harvest loss and profiteers
Last month, in the middle of the Christmas festive season, the price
of vegetables in Colombo and other urban areas skyrocketed. The reason
was that the government introduced a regulation requiring the transport
of all vegetables to be carried out in plastic or wooden crates rather
than gunny bags (hardly ever used nowadays) or polythene sacks.
The regulation was introduced in order to reduce the incidence of
spoilage in transport and handling and was expected to benefit farmers
and vendors in the long run. This followed on from studies which showed
that about half all post-harvest losses, which ranged from 16 percent
(ladies fingers) to 41 percent (cabbages and leeks), in the steps in the
marketing chain between the
The sources of post-harvest loss in the collection and transportation
stages were identified as exposure to sun, rough handling during loading
and unloading, transportation in poly sacks, tight packing and
overloading, compression damage during packing and stacking, damage due
to vibration and heat build up during transportation.
Vegetable farmers
The Institute of Post-Harvest Technology (IPHT) found that
transportation losses could be reduced from 15-20 percent with the use
of poly sacks to 3-6 percent with the use of plastic crates. The profit
from a single lorry load was found to increase by 25 percent.
Three-wheelers and Land-Masters were exempt from the law, which applied
only to lorries. The transporters, refusing to comply, went on strike
(and in certain areas, also on the rampage) until the regulation was put
on hold.
|
Vegetables
for sale |
This episode illustrates the extent to which vegetable farmers are
still dependent on middlemen. Even in times of glut, the middlemen,
while buying the farmers’ produce dirt-cheap sell it in Colombo at very
high prices. Consequently, Sri Lanka has one of the highest levels of
retail vegetable pricing in the region, surpassed only by Maldives.
Not so long ago, when farmers were receiving only about Rs 10 per
kilo of Tomatoes, the price in Colombo was Rs 50 per kg. It does not
take much arithmetic to figure out that the Rs 35 difference is far
higher than warranted by the cost of transport from Dambulla or Nuwara
Eliya (which is in fact about a rupee per kilogram).
The old Marketing Department (MD) was established to combat the
extreme exploitation of farmers by middlemen and to reduce the
occurrence of debt-peonage. At the time, most farmers were in the thrall
of the middlemen, who advanced them money at usurious rates for their
produce and collected it very cheap.
The problem of usury has been alleviated somewhat as banks
(particularly the state-owned banks) have proliferated in rural areas,
so that finding credit is not as big a problem as it used to be.
Nevertheless, the problem of exploitation by the transport-middleman
remains.
Capital accumulation
Given the small average size of Sri Lankan agricultural holdings,
transport to the market remains the central obstacle to achieving high
rates of capital accumulation in the sector; the surplus from
cultivation is taken mainly by the profiteer in the middle.
The IPHT research indicated that the implementation of the packaging
change from poly sacks to crates at the farmer’s level was impractical.
Farmers could not afford the cost of crates – an almost 18-fold increase
over poly sacks, even though the overall lifetime cost is only 15
percent of the latter.
Indeed, the average farmer cannot afford to invest in all the
measures the IPHT says can reduce post-harvest loss; for example,
packing house facilities having basic requirements such as washing
tanks, sorting and grading devices and cold storage facilities. They
could not even afford to install the low-technology (using a clay pot!)
evaporative cooling unit, developed by the IPHT and the University of
Peradeniya.
Obviously the onus should be on the middleman to introduce new
technologies and better practices to reduce post-harvest loss. However,
it appears that the middlemen, the collectors, transporters and vendors
are chary of doing so.
Their reasoning is not hard to find. The profit levels estimated by
the IPHT for the operations of middlemen were far below the actual
figures.
Packaging technology
Loss in transportation is minimal in comparison with the return, so
investing in more technology is a mere burden without commensurate
returns. The levels of profit can be measured by the fact that the big
supermarket chains are often able – despite higher overheads on such
things as air conditioning and refrigeration - to supply vegetables at
the same or lower prices as at retail greengrocers’ boutiques.
This is because they buy direct from the producers or from collection
centres, thereby eliminating the bulk of the supply chain. The MD was
established on precisely this premise, with the additional aim of
providing storage and packaging technology (for example its canneries)
in order to have year-round goods supply. Since the MD is no more, the
government shift its emphasis from the private sector to the
co-operatives.
The Co-operative Marketing Federation (Markfed) could become much
more active and step into the breach. It could establish the necessary
packing houses (complete with cooling facilities) close to the
producers, say at the central point in a village. This would enable
better packing and storage practices to be implemented at the base level
– as well as improved hygiene.
The co-op system could then become the hub of a vegetable supply
system oriented towards both producer and consumer - giving the former
high prices and the latter low ones.
Unfortunately, this is predicated on the response of the mafia of
vegetable middlemen. If this body of gentlemen can wreck such a small
thing as a regulation on the transport of vegetables, how far would it
go to prevent an effective solution to the needs of both producers and
consumers of vegetables?
|